Matching Practices for Secondary Schools – Sweden

This country profile is part of a collective effort by the network members to map matching practices across Europe. If you find it useful and want to refer to it in your own work, please refer to it as “Håkan Forsberg (2018), Matching Practices for Upper Secondary Schools, Sweden MiP Country Profile 27.

Download full profile pdf


Relevant country background

Education policy in Sweden is decided at a national level but its implementation is carried out by municipalities. The Swedish National Agency for Education sets the educational policy, designs the national curricula and issues regulations. However, implementation and interpretation of national policies are mainly carried out at a municipal level. In all, there are 20 counties and 290 municipalities in Sweden (approx. 10 million inhabitants). The municipalities are obliged by law to provide for childcare/preschool, compulsory and upper secondary education for their residents. Implementation is delegated to the local responsible authority of the school (municipalities or independent agents such as companies, staff co-operatives or foundations).

Main characteristics of the school system. Education in Sweden consists of a publicly-funded large-scale system that caters to everyone from early childhood to young adulthood.

Education is compulsory for age 7 till age 16. This is followed by voluntary upper secondary education which is free of charge and consists of 18 national study programmes, including both academic and vocational tracks. In addition, there are five different preparation programmes for those not eligible for a national study programme. At the local level, it is possible for school operators to design and develop variants of study programmes that deviate from the national study programmes [1].

Grades. They are given from year six in compulsory school using a six-grade scale from A-F, with grade F indicating inadequate performance. In order to qualify for upper secondary education, a student must have grades between A-E in the subjects English, mathematics and Swedish or Swedish as a second language. In addition, depending on whether they want to attend an academic or a vocational study programme, students need to have at least grades A-E in five further subjects [1].

Students who do not meet these requirements can apply for one of the preparation programmes in order to obtain the necessary qualifications.

In upper secondary education, subjects are divided into courses, and students are graded in each course on a scale from A to F, as in compulsory school. However, in upper secondary education a grade of F is equal to failure. Extra credits are given in upper secondary education for reaching specific levels in the subjects of modern languages, mathematics and English [1]. Upper secondary school study programmes comprise 2 500 credits, which is the sum of the credits for all courses. In order to graduate from upper secondary school, one must have obtained 90 percent of all credits with a pass grade (A-E), as well as have reached a pass in certain subjects. Graduation from upper secondary education automatically qualifies a student for access to higher education, although constraints may apply depending on the track (academic versus vocational) [1].

Although upper secondary education is voluntary in Sweden, participation is high. In 2017, 97.6 per cent of all 16-year olds entered upper secondary education [2]. This reflects the fact that upper secondary education is perceived as the minimum level of education needed to access the labour market. In fact, making upper secondary education mandatory is under discussion. At the same time, more than 20 percent of students entering upper secondary education drop out before completing their study programme [3]. Approximately one third of all upper secondary graduates continue directly onto higher education or post-secondary education [2].

Voucher system and independent school operators. Since the mid-1990’s, Sweden has had a publicly-funded voucher system (there were several reforms between 1991 and 1995 that are usually jointly referred to as the Free School Act). The voucher system guarantees free education and facilitates school choice at both local and national levels [4].

Simultaneously to the introduction of the voucher system, entry into the education market was deregulated: privately-owned operators (companies, staff co-operatives or foundations) were allowed to set up and manage so-called independent schools (preschools, compulsory schools and upper secondary schools), under the condition that they abide by the national curricula and regulations.

Independent schools are financed by vouchers on the same basis as municipal schools. This means that students take their funding with them when moving from one school to another.

As of 2017, 73 percent of students attended a municipality-operated school (versus 27 percent an independent school) nationwide. There are important local variations. For example, in the municipality of Stockholm, which is the most populous area in Sweden, the equivalent share students in municipality-operated schools was 44 percent.

There are variations across municipalities in the way the voucher system works. First, the financial value of vouchers varies across municipalities, which means that the budget a student contributes to her school depends on her municipality of residence. Funding for the voucher system derives from municipality taxes (70 %), government grants (14 %) and fees for childcare/ after-school centre (16 %) [7]. The amount is a combination of the actual cost of education per pupil in the specific municipality and the average cost of a similar education nationwide. As a result, spending on compulsory and upper secondary education differs between municipalities [8].

Second, some municipalities restrict access to municipality-operated schools to their residents. At the same time, independent schools can recruit pupils regardless of local administrative regulations but the value of vouchers may differ due to the students’ municipality of residence and these schools cannot discriminate students based on the value of their vouchers. Cross-municipality competition for students has become an important dimension of the competition for students between providers of later year compulsory education and upper secondary education, especially in urban areas [5] [6].

The enrolment policy for upper secondary education. It is defined in the national Education Act. The Act states that children and young adults are entitled to a free education, at both compulsory and upper secondary levels (Education Act, Chapter 7, 3§). Admissions procedures regarding catchment areas or selection by grades differ across municipalities [9]. Admission based on grades is only applicable when a school or a study programme is oversubscribed.

This profile describes the enrolment practices for upper secondary schools. For admission practices for compulsory schools, see Anderson (2017, MiP profile 24).

Summary box

Organization of education Coexistence of municipal and private school operators within the same public-school system. A voucher system promotes school choice and determines the exact funding that each school receives.
Stated objectives of enrollment policy Equal access to education
Who’s in charge? Local authorities (municipalities) administer the application process while admissions are made by individual schools
In place since 2010
Available capacity Upper and lower limits to class sizes imposed by the school operator.
Timing of enrollment Choices submitted in February. Preliminary results released in April, final decisions in July.
Information available to parents prior to enrollment period School and municipality websites. The Swedish National Agency for Education provides school-level statistics on gender, nationality and parental education, together with enrolment numbers and average grades.
Restrictions on preference expression Depends on the local administration of enrolment but in general one can list several options in decreasing order.
Matching procedure Mostly non-algorithmic as long as legal and local guidelines are respected.
Priorities and quotas A limited number of seats set aside for students with special needs or social circumstances, and for Swedish students from abroad.
Tie-breaking Decided by the school operator. Oversubscribed schools typically use grades to break ties.

Description of current practices

After the deregulation and decentralisation of education at the beginning of the 1990’s following the Free School Act, the supply of the locally designed study programmes increased while the number of national study programmes decreased.

The choice of school and study programme follows a nationally coordinated time schedule designed by the Swedish Association of Local Authorities and Regions. Students must rank their preferred choices of schools and study programmes. By mid-February, applications are submitted to the local administration of enrolment which, depending on demography, can be a single municipality or an administratively joint group of municipalities. Schools are by law (Education Act Chapter 15, 14 §) responsible for admissions but these are usually carried out by the local administration of enrolment. Schools are not allowed by law to turn down a student if there are open seats and they meet the formal qualifications. Oversubscription criteria are described in general terms in the Education Act which makes room for local variations and interpretations among school operators. In case of oversubscription, the school operator has the final call which usually is decided by grades as tie-breaking, but work samples or auditions can also be applied when it comes to specific study programmes such as arts or special craftsmanship. Furthermore, schools must make a limited number of seats available for students with special needs or circumstances or whose grades are incomparable to the regular ones from Swedish primary school.

Preliminary results are published in April. In May, a second round is open where students can alter/reprioritize their choices. Final admission decisions take place in July and the school year starts in August [15].

One important distinction between schools operated by municipalities and independent providers is that the latter can recruit pupils nation-wide. The municipalities, on the other hand, are obliged to take their “own” pupils and can only accept pupils from other municipalities based on local regulations and agreements.

Performance

Numbers from the Swedish National Agency for Education show a decrease in the share of first choice admissions, from 78 percent 2011 to 65.2 percent in 2017. As shown in figure 1, the decrease is stronger in urban areas, such as the city of Stockholm.

Research as well as evaluations made by the Swedish National Agency for Education show that the introduction of the voucher system and the facilitation of school choice have led to increased differences between schools with regard to the socio-economic background of students and their school performance. Although this phenomenon is partly driven by the increase in housing segregation in urban areas, research shows that school choice exacerbates the effect [12, 13& 17]. Furthermore, there is a strong correlation between social background and outcomes in school [13, 14, 16 & 18].

Figure 1: Share of first choice admission (source: Swedish National Agency for Education)

The impact of school choice seems to be greater in upper secondary education where there are more choices to be made, while compulsory schooling is structured by the effects of housing segregation to a greater extent [12, 14 & 16]. These differences can be illustrated by looking at the share of students attending independent schools. The figure below shows the share of students who attend independent schools in upper secondary education respectively compulsory schooling, 2011–2017, in the city of Stockholm and in the whole of Sweden. The numbers for Stockholm underlines the impact of school choice in urban areas.

Figure 2: Share of students attending independent schools, Stockholm and Sweden, 2011–17 (source: Swedish National Agency for Education)

In the case of upper secondary education in Stockholm, the significance of geographic location has increased considerably since the introduction of school vouchers. Before the reforms, geographic location had less impact on the competition among schools for new pupils, since proximity decided which pupils a school could recruit and which school the pupils could attend. Thus, housing segregation had a direct impact on schools’ recruitment. The emergence of the educational market, and the gradual deregulation regarding both the establishment of new schools and the geographic restrictions on pupils’ choices, resulted in location becoming crucial for schools in their competition for students but less crucial for parents. Independent schools could differentiate themselves by setting up schools in areas that are considered attractive, e.g. in Stockholm City and its neighbouring areas. The municipal schools, generally established before the school voucher reforms, could rarely do anything about their geographic location; either the location constituted an asset for the school – which was the case for old municipal institutions in the inner city and centrally located municipal schools in surrounding municipalities – or not. The attraction of central Stockholm turned the inner city into a centre of the education market. In this centre, both upper secondary schools and pupils with most resources, in terms of socio-economic backgrounds and grades, can be found [5] [14]. Examples of the attractiveness of Stockholm city and its concentration of resourceful students are illustrated in Figure 3 and 4. When comparing the numbers in Figure 4 one should keep in mind that the schools in Stockholm city comprise 50 percent of all schools in the county.

Figure 3: Number of students in Stockholm city schools from other municipalities (source: Forsberg (2015, p. 109)

Recent policy changes

In 2011, a reform put limits on locally designed study programmes. Additionally, a more granular grading system was introduced and the curriculum was revised to make access to higher education after completing a vocational program harder.

Figure 4: Level of parents’ education, Stockholm city and Stockholm county, 2009-14 (source:Statistics Sweden)

Perceived issues

The effect of school choice and the entry of independent operators owned by private agents into the public sector of education are hot topics in Sweden. There is a debate on whether the decentralisation and deregulation of the Swedish school system are related to the deteriorating performance of the Sweden education system in international comparisons such as PISA and TIMSS.

Another frequently discussed topic concerns the profits made by the private companies running the independent schools, since their operations are financed by tax money. Today, there is no restriction on entry into the education market and several corporate groups running multiple schools have emerged. The largest corporate group is Academedia which runs 650 schools catering for 176 000 children and students at all school levels and has 15 800 employees. In 2017, Academedia had a turnover close to 940 million EUR and made a profit equal to 41 million EUR.

Since tuition fees are not allowed in the Swedish school system, grades have become an essential dimension of competition. Grade inflation is becoming an issue. Several studies provide evidence for grade inflation in Sweden [10] and suggest that independent schools are more generous with grading than municipal schools [11]. Furthermore, the national tests, which are an important source of data for grading pupils in compulsory and upper secondary education, are corrected internally by the supervising teacher, creating a source of conflict of interest.

Legal texts

The Swedish parliament
The Education act of Sweden

The Swedish National Agency for Education
A ll national information on curricula, subject plans and courses

Other resources and references

[1] Website of The Swedish National Agency for Education. (2018), viewed 12.6.2018.

[2] Website of The Swedish National Agency for Education. (2018), viewed 13.6.2018.

[3] Statistics Sweden (2017), “Young people left behind? The situation on the labour market for those born in the 1990s without completed upper secondary education”. Theme report 2017:4.

[4] Blomqvist, P. (2004). “The Choice Revolution: Privatization of Swedish Welfare Services in the 1990s”. Social Policy & Administration, 38 (2), 139–155.

[5] Forsberg, H. (2015). Kampen om eleverna: gymnasiefältet och skolmarknadens framväxt i Stockholm, 1987–2011. Uppsala: Uppsala universitet.

[6] Bunar, N. (2010). “The Controlled School Market and Urban Schools in Sweden”. Journal of School Choice, 4 (1), 47–73.

[7] Website of Swedish Association of Local Authorities and Regions (2018), viewed 13.6.18.

[8] The Swedish National Agency for Education (2018). “Kommunernas resursfördelning till grundskolor”. Rapport nr 391.

[9] The Swedish National Agency for Education. (2013). Det svåra valet. Elevers val av utbildning på olika slags gymnasiemarknader. Rapport 394.

[10] The Institute for Evaluation of Labour Market and Education Policy (IFAU) (2010). Den svenska utbildningspolitikens arbetsmarknadseffekter:vad säger forskningen? Rapport 2010:13.

[11] Jonas Vlachos (2018). Trust-Based Evaluation in a Market-Oriented School System. IFN Working Paper nr 1217.

[12] Böhlmark, A., Holmlund, H., & Lindahl, M. (2016). Parental choice, neighbourhood segregation or cream skimming? An analysis of school segregation after a generalized choice reform. Journal of Population Economics, 29(4), 1155–1190.

[13] Östh, J., Andersson, E., & Malmberg, B. (2013). School Choice and Increasing Performance Difference: A Counterfactual Approach. Urban Studies, 50(2), 407–425.

[14] Forsberg, H. (2018). School competition and social stratification in the deregulated upper secondary school market in Stockholm. British Journal of Sociology of Education, 1–17.

[15] Swedish Association of Local Authorities and Regions (2018). Handbok för gymnasieantagning 2017-2018. Gällande bestämmelser samt kommentarer om mottagande/antagning till gymnasieskolan och gymnasiesärskolan.

[16] Söderström, Martin, and Roope Uusitalo. 2010. “School Choice and Segregation: Evidence from an Admission Reform*.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics 112 (1): 55–76.

[17] Hennerdal, Pontus, Bo Malmberg, and Eva K. Andersson. 2018. “Competition and School Performance: Swedish School Leavers from 1991–2012.” Scandinavian Journal of Educational Research 0 (0): 1–17.10.

[18] The Swedish National Agency for Education. (2018). Analyser av familjebakgrundens betydelse för skolresultaten och skillnader mellan skolor.

 


 

The Israeli Medical Internship Match

This country profile is part of a collective effort by the network members to map matching practices across Europe. If you find it useful and want to refer to it in your own work, please refer to it as “Slava Bronfman, Avinatan Hassidim, Gideon Kalif, and Assaf Romm (2017), Matching practices for entry-labor markets – The Israeli Medical Internship Match, MiP Country Profile 25.”

Download full profile pdf


Relevant country background

In Israel there are roughly 500 medical school graduates each year. These graduates must participate in a one-year long internship program before they receive their medical degrees. There are also 200 additional graduates who complete their medical studies abroad but wish to practice medicine in Israel and are required to participate in an internship as well. For this purpose, each student is assigned to one out of 24 hospitals across the country (the number of hospitals that are eligible to receive interns may change from time to time). The number of students assigned to each hospital is proportional to the average number of patients in that hospital, except for hospitals located at the periphery of the country which receive more interns than their proportional quota. The hospitals vary in their location, working environment, the specializations of medical staff, the amount of attention given to instructing interns, and the terms of the internship.

Read more

Members

 

First nameLast nameUniversityDepartment\UnitCountry
AzarAbizadaADA UniversitySchool of BusinessAzerbaijan
MustafaAfakanSabanci UniversityFaculty of Arts and Social SciencesTurkey
KarstenAlbaekDanish National Centre for Social ResearchDenmark
José AlcaldeUniversity of AlicanteDepartment of Quantitative Methods and Economic TheorySpain
JorgeAlcalde-UnzuPublic University of NavarraDepartment of EconomicsSpain
RebeccaAllenInstitute of Education University College LondonDepartment of Quantitative Social ScienceUK
TommyAnderssonLund UniversityDepartment of EconomicsSweden
HayriArslanVanderbiltUSA
OrhanAygünBoğaziçi UniversityEconomics DepartmentTurkey
HarisAzizData 61 Computer Science and EngineeringAustralia
SophieBadeRoyal Holloway, University of LondonDepartment of EconomicsUK
ChristianBasteckUniversité libre de BruxellesECARESBelgium
PéterBiroHungarian Academy of SciencesInstitute of EconomicsHungary
FrancisBlochUniversite Paris I and Paris School of EconomicsFrance
InacioBo Berlin Social Science Center (WZB)
Research Unit Market Behavior
Germany
SimonBurgessUniversity of BristolDepartment of EconomicsUK
CaterinaCalsamigliaUniversitat Autònoma de BarcelonaDepartament d’Economia i Història EconòmicaSpain
EmilioCalvanoUniversity of BolognaDepartment of EconomicsItaly
BurakCanMaastricht UniversitySchool of Business and EconomicsNetherlands
AndreaCanidioINSEADFrance
EstelleCantillonUniversité‚ libre de BruxellesECARESBelgium
Katarína CechlárováUniverzita Pavla Jozefa ŠafárikInstitute of MathematicsSlovakia
LiChenUniversity of GothenburgDepartment of EconomicsSweden
JohnColdronSheffield Hallam UniversityCentre for Education and Inclusion ResearchUK
MelvynColesUniversity of EssexDepartment of EconomicsUK
JulienCombePSEFrance
BenoitDecerfUniversity of NamurDepartment of EconomicsBelgium
KoenDeclercqKULeuvenResearch Center of EconometricsBelgium
David DelacretazOxford University Department of Economics and Nuffield CollegeUK
NadjaDwengerUniversity of HohenheimDepartment of EconomicsGermany
JanEeckhoutUniversity College London and Barcelona GSE-UPFDepartment of EconomicsUK and Spain
Özgün Ekici Özyeǧin UniversityTurkey
AytekErdilUniversity of CambridgeFaculty of EconomicsUK
GabrielleFackUniversité Paris 1 Panthéon Sorbonne and Paris School of Economics France
TamásFleinerEötvös Loránd University Department of Operation researchHungary
HåkanForsbergUppsala UniversitetDepartment of EducationSweden
LucienFrys Humboldt University BerlinDepartment of EconomicsGermany
AlfredGalichonNew York UniversityEconomics DepartmentUSA
ThomasGallUniversity of SouthamptonEconomics Division, School of Social SciencesUK
Kristiaan MichelGlorieErasmus University RotterdamErasmus School of EconomicsNetherlands
EllenGreavesInstitute for Fiscal StudiesUK
JulienGrenetParis School of EconomicsFrance
Fane NajaGroesCopenhagen Business SchoolDepartment of EconomicsDenmark
GuillaumeHaeringerBaruch College, Zicklin School of BusinessDepartments of Economics and FinanceUS
RustamHakimovWZBResearch Unit Market BehaviorGermany
YinghuaHeRice UniversityDepartment of EconomicsUSA
PhilippHellerHumboldt University BerlinFaculty of Economics and Business AdministrationGermany
AllanHernández ChantoUniversity of QueenslandDepartment of EconomicsAustralia
VictorHillerUniversité Paris II Panthéon-AssasLEMMAFrance
DanielHornHungarian Academy of SciencesInstitute of Economics,
Center for Economic and Regional Studies
Hungary
MikkelHøst GandilUniversity of Copenhagen
Department of EconomicsDenmark
BrittaHoyerUniversität PaderbornCenter of International EconomicsGermany
KatharinaHuesmannUniversity of CologneCologne Graduate School in Economics, Management and Social SciencesGermany
MariaHumlumAarhus UniversityDepartment of Economics and BusinessDenmark
IftikharHussainSussex UniversityDepartment of EconomicsUK
ElenaInarraUniversity of the Basque CountryFaculty of EconomicsSpain
RobIrvingUniversity of GlasgowSchool of Computing ScienceScotland
ZsuzsannaJankóEötvös Loránd UniversityDepartment of Operations ResearchHungary
JohnKennesAarhus UniversityDepartment of Economics and BusinessDenmark
SofyaKiselgofNational Research UniversityHigher School of EconomicsRussia
BettinaKlausUniversity of LausanneFaculty of Business and Economics (HEC)Switzerland
ThiloKleinOECD and Paris 21France
FlipKlijnUniversitat Autònoma de BarcelonaInstitute for Economic AnalysisSpain
László Á.KóczyObuda UniversityKeleti Facultyof EconomicsHungary
DorotheaKübler Berlin Social Science Center (WZB)Research Unit: Market BehaviorGermany
MorimitsuKurinoUniversity of TsukubaFaculty of Engineering, Information and SystemsJapan
AlexeyKushnirCarnegie Mellon UniversityTepper School of BusinessUS
AugustineKwanashieUniversity of GlasgowSchool of Computing ScienceScotland
PatrickLegrosUniversit‚é libre de BruxellesECARESBelgium
FrançoisManiquetUniversit‚é catholique de Louvain and COREDépartements des sciences ‚économiquesBelgium
DavidManloveUniversity of GlasgowSchool of Computing ScienceScotland
VirgineMarelliUniversity of NamurBelgium
RubénMartínez-CárdenasUniversity of YorkDepartment of Economics and Related StudiesUK
FranciscoMartinez-MoraUniversity of LeicesterDepartment of EconomicsUK
JordiMassóUniversitat Autònoma de BarcelonaDepartament d’Economia i Història EconòmicaSpain
AnaMauleonUniversité Saint-Louis - BruxellesCenter for Research in Economics (CEREC)Belgium
IainMcBrideUniversity of GlasgowSchool of Computing ScienceScotland
TimoMennleUniversity of ZurichDepartment of InformaticsSwitzerland
AntonioMirallesUniversitat Autònoma de BarcelonaDepartment of EconomicsSpain
MatthiasMnuchUniversity of BonnEconomics departmentGermany
ElenaMolisUniversidad de GranadaDepartment of Economic Theory and HistorySpain
DanielMonteSao Paulo School of Economics - FGVBrazil
MichiruNagatsuUniversity of HelsinkiDepartment of Political and Economic StudiesFinland
HeinrichNaxUniversity of Oxford Department of Humanities, Social and Political SciencesUK
AlexandruNichiforUniversity of St AndrewsDepartment of EconomicsUK
AntonioNicolòUniversita degli Studi di PadovaDepartment of EconomicsItaly
GreggO'MalleyUniversity of GlasgowSchool of Computing ScienceScotland
HesselOosterbeekUniversity of AmsterdamAmsterdam School of EconomicsNetherlands
JoanaPaisUniversidade de LisboaInstituto Superior de Economia e GestãoPortugal
KatarzynaPaluchUniversity of WroclawInstitute of Computer SciencePoland
JuanPereyraUniversit‚é libre de BruxellesECARESBelgium
ÁgnesPintérUniversidad Autónoma de MadridDepartment of Economic AnalysisSpain
KairePõderTallinn University of TechnologySchool of Economics and Business AdministrationEstonia
BaryPradelskiETH ZurichComputational Social Science GroupSwitzerland
SalmaiQariMax-Planck-Institut for Tax Law and Public FinanceBerlin School of Economics and LawGermany
EveRamaekersUniversit‚é catholique de Louvain and COREDépartements des sciences ‚économiquesBelgium
Baharak (Bahar)RastegariUniversity of SouthamptonDepartment of Electronics and Computer ScienceUK
Anne-KatrinRoeslerUniversity of MichiganDepartment of EconomicsUSA
AntonioRomeroUniversidad Carlos III de MadridDepartamento de EconomíaSpain
AssafRommHebrew University of JerusalemDepartment of EconomicsIsrael
HannuSalonenUniversity of TurkuDepartment of EconomicsFinland
IsmaelSanz LabradorInstituto Nacional de Evaluación EducativaMinisterio de Educación, Cultura y DeporteSpain
Jan ChristophSchlegelCity, University of LondonDepartment of EconomicsUK
Ildi SchlotterBudapest University of Technology and EconomicsDepartment of Computer Science and Information TheoryHungary
FelixSchmidtGutenberg University MainzChair of Public EconomicsGermany
KerstinSchneiderUniversity of WuppertalShumpeter School of Business and EconomicsGermany
SvenSeukenUniversity of ZurichDepartment of InformaticsSwitzerland
RanShorrerPenn StateUSA
MargaretStevensOxford UniversityLincoln CollegeUK
Veskioja
TarmoTallinn University of TechnologyInstitute of Informatics Estonia
BenjamínTello Banco de MexicoMexico
OlivierTercieuxParis School of EconomicsFrance
CamilleTerrierLSECenter for Economic Performance & Political SciencesUK
AlexTeytelboymUniversity of OxfordInstitute for New Economic Thinking (INET) UK
NorovsambuuTumennasanDalhousie UniversityDepartment of Economics Canada
MartinVan der LindenVanderbilt UniversityDepartment of EconomicsUSA
Winnievan DijkChicago UniversityBecker Friedman InstituteUSA
AgnèsVan ZantenSciences PoObservatoire Sociologique du ChangementFrance
HannuVartiainenUniversity of HelsinkiHelsinki Center of Economic Research (HECER) and Finnish Doctoral Programme in Economics (FDPE)Finland
RuneVejlinAarhus UniversityDepartment of Economics and BusinessDenmark
Jean-PierreVerhaegheKU LeuvenCenter for Teaching Effectiveness
Belgium
FredericVermeulenKU Leuven Department of EconomicsBelgium
AndréVeskiTallinn University of TechnologyInstitute of Informatics
Estonia
SunčicaVujićUniversity of AntwerpenDepartment of EconomicsBelgium
MarkusWalzlUniversity of InnsbruckDepartment of EconomicsAustria
MatWeldonLancaster University Department of EconomicsUK
Alexander
WestkampUniversity of CologneGermany
Özgür YılmazKoç UniversityDepartment of EconomicsTurkey
PabloZoidoOECDDG Education, Early Childhood and Schools Division
France
JieZhangUniversity of SouthamptonDepartment of Computer ScienceUK

Conference Committee

Matching in Practice typically organizes 2 workshops per year. To allow for both continuity and diversity in the scientific program committee, the conference committee is made of a member of the conference host institution, as well as the hosts of the past two workshops.

Matching Practices for Elementary Schools – Sweden

This country profile is part of a collective effort by the network members to map matching practices across Europe. If you find it useful and want to refer to it in your own work, please refer to it as “Andersson, Tommy (2017), Matching practices for elementary schools – Sweden, MiP Country Profile 24.”

Download full profile pdf


Relevant country background

In Sweden, children have the right to start preschool from the age of six. Preschool is not compulsory but in practice around 98 percent of six-year-olds attend preschool. Municipalities are obliged to offer and arrange for preschool for all pupils that request to be enrolled. School becomes compulsory for children from the autumn term of the year they reach the age of seven, and compulsory school attendance ceases at the end of the spring term of their 9th school year (i.e., by the time children are 16 years old). Preschools are typically combined with primary schools but secondary schools are separate. As a consequence, most children have to change schools upon finishing primary school.

Read more

University admission practices – France

This country profile is part of a collective effort by the network members to map matching practices across Europe. If you find it useful and want to refer to it in your own work, please refer to it as “Frys, Lucien and Staat, Christian (2016), University admission practices – France, MiP Country Profile 23.”

Download full profile pdf


Relevant country background

In France all students follow the same program until the age of 15. Afterwards they enter high school (lycée) for another three years where they specialize and prepare for a national standard test (baccalauréat).[1] The baccalauréat gives students access to higher education.

France has a distinctive higher education system. It is divided between public universities governed by the ministry of higher education and research, technical high schools and preparatory schools governed by the ministry of education, the grandes écoles governed by other ministries or chambers of commerce,[2] and a few private institutions. Grandes écoles do not recruit directly after the baccalauréat: Students must be admitted first to preparatory schools and prepare during two years for an entrance examination.

Read more

Matching Practices for secondary schools – Germany

This country profile is part of a collective effort by the network members to map matching practices across Europe. If you find it useful and want to refer to it in your own work, please refer to it as “Basteck, Christian, Katharina Huesmann, and Heinrich Nax (2015), Matching Practices for secondary schools – Germany, MiP Country Profile 21.”

Download full profile pdf


German school system

Germany is a federal state consisting of 16 States (Bundesländer). Education policy is decided at the level of the States. Depending on the State, education is compulsory for nine or ten years with the first four or six years being primary school. Primary and secondary school education in Germany is mostly public and free of charge. There are some private schools, but only about five to six percent of German students attend private schools (this number is increasing however). [1],[2] Private schools are allowed to charge school fees, but most of them receive large subsidies and school fees are kept relatively low. They can also select students according to their own set of criteria. This country profile describes school admissions for public schools.

Read more

Matching practices of teachers to Schools – France

This country profile is part of a collective effort by the network members to map matching practices across Europe. If you find it useful and want to refer to it in your own work, please refer to it as “Camille Terrier (2014), Matching Practices for secondary public school teachers – France, MiP Country Profile 20.”

Download full profile pdf


Relevant country background

The French education system is divided into public schools and private schools. Private schools make up 16% of teachers.[1] Anyone who wishes to become a teacher has to pass a competitive examination. Those who succeed are allocated a teaching position for a probation period of one year, at the end of which they get tenure or not. Once they get tenure, teachers in public schools are civil servants, which is not the case of teachers

Read more

Matching Practices for Secondary Schools – Finland

This country profile is part of a collective effort by the network members to map matching practices across Europe. If you find it useful and want to refer to it in your own work, please refer to it as ”Salonen, Mikko A.A. (2014), Matching Practices for Secondary Schools – Finland, MiP Country Profile 19.

Download full profile pdf


Relevant country background

The education system in Finland is made of daycare programs (for babies and toddlers), a one-year preschool and a nine-year compulsory comprehensive school (from age 7 till age 16). After comprehensive school, a student can start upper secondary school, vocational secondary school or decide to work. Approximately half of the pupils go to upper secondary school upon graduation from comprehensive school and the other half

Read more

Matching practices for Elementary Schools – Estonia

This country profile is part of a collective effort by the network members to map matching practices across Europe. If you find it useful and want to refer to it in your own work, please refer to it as “Lauri, T., Põder, K. and Veski, A (2014), Matching practices for Elementary Schools – Estonia, MiP Country Profile 18.

Download full profile pdf


Relevant country background

The Estonian education system is largely decentralized. Local authorities are responsible for providing general education (from pre-primary to upper secondary), monitoring compulsory school attendance, and maintaining pre-primary institutions and general education schools. School education is compulsory and municipality-funded from age 7 till the end of lower-secondary school (in total 9 years).

Read more